Have you ever scrolled on UberEats for hours wondering what to order, before giving up and going back to the same thing you ordered last week? Or have you struggled endlessly with your friends when picking a restaurant to eat at? Have you thought about trying a new restaurant for weeks but never been able to bring yourself to do it?
The universal challenge of deciding
a dinner location is a daily phenomenon for many, and while you wonder simply
what would satisfy your hunger best, you may not realise why this seemingly
menial task is so difficult, or what drives you to finally settle on a choice.
Part of the challenge comes from the
sheer gap between the selection of restaurants you have tried before, versus
the wide range of different restaurants you could choose, but have yet to try.
Trying a new restaurant may lead to a better dining experience, but there is
also a risk of dissatisfaction, and risk-averse people are more willing to
choose stable options to avoid possible losses (Menezes and Hanson, 1970).
Hence, you may notice people tend to return to familiar places rather than try
new ones, allowing them to avoid uncertainty, according to the logic of
expected utility theory that both risks and benefits are considered when you
make a decision (Grant and Van Zandt, 2007).
Another reason you may default to
familiar restaurants is because you have more information about the experience
you would get - you may know the menu, the prices, the lighting, seating, or
even the waiters a lot better than if you ventured to try a completely new
place. Moreover, you don’t know the quality of food in a new restaurant until
after you order and the food is served, and the plate that arrives may not
match your expectations, or may not match the description that the restaurant
portrays to you.
Unfortunately, you know in the back
of your mind that the new restaurant would want to present itself as a place
with high-quality food, but also that they would like to minimise their cost,
giving them an incentive to serve you something less delicious than they claim.
This information asymmetry between you and the new restaurant is much larger
than with a restaurant you frequent, contributing to more uncertainty, which
decreases the satisfaction you would expect to get when trying a new place
(Pishchulov and Richter, 2016). In response, restaurants may try to counter
this information asymmetry by displaying customer evaluations, giving away
samples, or being open about their ingredients and cooking methods.
Besides all the dangers of the
unfamiliar territory of new restaurants, there could be other mentalities and
mindsets that you hold which bring you back to the same place over and over.
Have you ever glorified a restaurant as having the greatest food of all time -
perhaps Babylon or Zaytoni? While they may indeed be of high quality, they are
likely not as incredible as the perception that you have of them - this
obsession-like framing is called salience. Alternatively, have you always
considered new choices by comparing them to a certain restaurant you already
know is good, making that restaurant a mental anchor for you? This may
encourage you to judge a new place by standards in which the old place excels
at (e.g. focusing on comparing prices for the same food, while neglecting
differences in quality or ambience), disrupting your view of both places
(Goolsbee, Levitt, and Syverson, 2015).
However, when you finally do make
the brave leap of faith and try a new restaurant - what helps you make that
decision? Market signalling acts to mitigate risks by indicating quality, making
it crucial when considering a new restaurant (Varian, 2020). Positive signals, like
recommendations from friends and family, glowing online reviews and social
proof from a busy dining area are likely to increase your willingness to try a
new establishment – with negative signals having the adverse effect.
Word-of-mouth recommendations often serve as strong signals as they are from
trusted sources, alleviating fears of disappointment. Consumer confidence is
further reinforced by online reviews and ratings. Platforms like Google or
Tripadvisor act as a credible indicator of quality, with low ratings deterring
customers. Additionally, visual cues – such as a crowded restaurant – act as an
implicant indicator that the food and service is satisfactory. Conversely, an
empty restaurant may frighten customers even if it has excellent food, due to
negative signalling.
Restaurants themselves also engage
in strategic signalling through branding, advertising, and partnerships with
influencers aimed at shaping customer perceptions. Upon deeper thinking, just
because someone else recommends a restaurant, this does not necessarily mean
you would enjoy it as much as they would, given you likely have some degree of
different tastes. And yet, we tend to respond positively to these signals,
since there does tend to be a correlation between good reviews and good
quality.
In conclusion, the next time you
struggle to choose a restaurant for dinner or go back to the same staple
location, keep in mind all the reasons you prefer the safety of the familiar
place, like the additional information you have about the place and the reduced
risks, and that there are ways to make trying a new place more palatable, such
as asking friends and family who have tried the place before, or by looking for
signals from online reviews.
References:
Menezes,
C.F. and Hanson, D.L. (1970). On the Theory of Risk Aversion. International
Economic Review, 11(3), p.481. doi:https://doi.org/10.2307/2525326.
Grant,
S. and Van Zandt, T. (2007). Expected Utility Theory. [online]
papers.ssrn.com. Available at:
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1033982.
Pishchulov,
G. and Richter, K. (2016). Optimal contract design in the joint economic lot
size problem with multi-dimensional asymmetric information. European Journal
of Operational Research, 253(3), pp.711–733. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2016.02.053.
Goolsbee,
A., Levitt, S. and Syverson, C. (2015). Microeconomics. Macmillan Higher
Education.
Varian,
H.R. (2020). Intermediate microeconomics: with calculus. New York: W.W.
Norton And Company.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.